Tuesday, June 12, 2007

Energy Self Reliance: Viray vs. Velasco

It was with keen interest that I read Dr. Francisco Viray’s review/critique of Mr. Geronimo Velasco’s most recent book on the quest for ‘energy self-reliance’. I must confess I haven’t yet read this book; but I’ve read a much earlier tome by the same author and on the same theme published in the late 70’s.

Viray’s critique---for that is how it should be called---highlights the recurring theme of the proper role of the state in the energy sector, and for that matter, in ‘leading’ sectors of the economy. The quotation marks are motivated by an appreciation of the fact that people tend to think that their sector is always major or leading.

Let me say now that I think that there are major points that Viray really misses. Unfortunately. But let me say too that Velasco’s so-called insights are drivel.

(Allow me this long parenthetical note. Just recently, an analytical report emanating from the Department of Budget and Management urged an urgent review of the Department of Agriculture’s food security objective, saying it was too costly and more to the point, misdirected. It is a point I agree with generally for I have yet to see any evidence that the subsidies really benefit rice farmers and that the tariff protection did not serve only to benefit favored rice importers.

Insofaras the energy sector is concerned, I was really surprised that during a lecture I was privileged to attend, the prominent American energy economist William Hogan made the case that energy should, in the main, be treated as just another commodity for which all social costs should be reflected. He was lamenting the fact that the United States government (or more precisely all American taxpayers) was paying for a very expensive political and defense policy, especially in the Middle East, for which the cost was distributed in a way which did not actually reflect consumption. Think about the war in Iraq! In effect, a private good was being treated as a public good. If the objective were only to address temporary shocks or supply disruptions, one could rely on the Strategic Petroleum Reserve, and charge inventory costs to taxpayers, said.

In his critique, Viray expresses agreement with the objective of ‘self-reliance’ but protests ‘political intervention’ in the affairs of government corporations in the energy sector. Is he saying that the state should give the corporations and the managers the resources and then leave them to their own devices? I think not, for Viray is too intelligent not to know about general political direction and accountability. Mysteriously, Viray speaks of a political context or environment and seems to say that experts (so-called) are always constrained by democratic principles. (I protest dictatorship only if I am not the dictator).

But let us first tackle ‘self-reliance,’ an objective with which he is in agreement with Velasco. Former experts at the corporate planning department of the National Power Corporation and other Philippine energy researchers will surely tell us that this objective is not without costs. Hydro, geothermal, local coal, natural gas etc. are not really the cheapest sources of electric power in any line-up of options. In other words, the objective has imposed and still imposes a cost in addition to lower cost options. I would have no problem with that for as long as these additional costs are properly explained and decided on in the political arena.

Of course, there is a sense in which I am totally in agreement with Dr. Viray. And that is if ‘political’ exclusively meant intervention in the day-to-day management of government corporations in the energy sector and in total disregard of performance and professional management principles. Even Velasco cannot disagree with that but...

Viray quotes Velasco on the fact he (Velasco) was forced to diminish protection for the local coal industry because of the structural adjustment program impositions, mainly of the World Bank and the IMF. As a persistent socialist and qualified nationalist, I would be among the first to protest multilateral impositions; but not when these are essentially correct. I can protest the fact of the imposition but defend its essence. It is a matter of integrity. I can say the ‘enemy’ is absolutely correct in some regard.

Who am I to write all of the above? (Read on).

A year after graduating from the University of San Carlos with a degree in chemical engineering, I joined the National Power Corporation as a chemical analyst for one of the first two power (diesel) barges in the Philippines, anchored in Cebu, in 1991. At the time Secretary Velasco was considered as a god of sorts. We had had training for almost a month when his chopper landed on the premises in Naga just as a super-barge unloaded the power barge straight from Japan.

In the same year I was hailed to the Visayas regional security office of NPC for having spoken at a rally against the notorious Amendment 6, which eventually allowed the dictator to rule by decree even after he had allowed the election of a national assembly in 1978. My interrogator was menacing and a real menace.

In my very short period with the NPC, where I was also assigned to the fuels laboratory serving the first NPC coal power plants (from Romania) I was exposed to all the corruption in procurement. I and another engineer were asked to sign an acceptance report for a hypochlorination plant for the cooling water requirements of the coal plant. We both refused.

Which brings me to this point. How can we assess people like Velasco, who continue to assert virtue?


Later, I joined the Ministry of Energy with the encouragement of someone who had been with the old communist party (but who had been expelled) as still a lowly bureaucrat with the Bureau of Energy Utilization in the Visayas.

In the same year, I was invited by the National Intelligence Security Agency (NISA) for a ‘meeting’ which was actually an interrogation. The agents showed me pictures of protest demonstrations and asked me to explain. At the same time, in the same compound, my girlfriend who happened to work in the same office was also being interrogated in the same compound. Her interrogator was opposite her on a swing, ‘persuaiding’ her to inform on me.

I am sure many Filipinos have similar stories. What should make them special is the willingness and capacity to tell us these now so we will not Velasco and others who came after him escape an accounting.

What follows is Viray's review of Velasco's new book.


It is a dilemma to critique a book authored by someone I worked for and admire as a person but with whom I disagreed with in major policy decisions during my term as Secretary of Energy under the Ramos administration. I can either end up defending myself—which will be construed as a biased critique—or avoid a debate on policy decisions by simply citing the differences in governance during his time and my time. However, such simplistic review would ignore the significance of the management approach and policies that helped the accomplishments cited in the book, which I completely agree with. Not because I worked for the author for some time, but because I was very much involved in the energy industry during my academic career at the University of the Philippines during the Marcos administration.

The book is a good treatise on how to manage government corporations, most especially in the energy industry, which is critical to the life of a country’s economy and the well being of its citizens. The story on Philippine National Oil Company (PNOC), Petron, and National Power Corporation (Napocor) showed that the state has to insulate from political intervention the energy industry’s government corporations if it wants them to accomplish their mission in the interest of national security and price affordability, and if it wants corporations to act as catalyst to support policies on energy development and management. The admission of the author that he would not have done the things he had done without Martial Law attests to this statement (48, 78). He can even get away with so-called anomalous Memorandum of Agreements (141) at the time. Moreover, the success of Petron from which the author inherited personnel with a private culture of efficiency and merit-based recognition compared to the lesser success of Napocor, which was a government corporation from the start, is another testament (140-41).

While I agree that the best way to influence the behavior of players in the market is for government to play a significant role through a full ownership of Petron and Napocor, such role can only be played if it is allowed to be run professionally and freed from political intervention and removed from the rules and regulations of government hiring, salary structures, procurement procedures, and the like (17-19, 205). Note: A lot of good people at Napocor left when it was placed under the Salary Standardization Law of the government.
The mere fact that when the Department of Energy was reinstituted in 1992, Congress inserted a provision whereby the budget of PNOC and Napocor had to be approved by Congress proves that insulating energy corporations from political intervention is easier said than done. Imagine Petron’s budget passing through Congress, its crude oil procurement done through government bidding procedures (19), or Petron being asked by government to subsidize oil prices during periods of crude oil increase just like what was mandated for Napocor. Under our version of a democracy and its resultant political environment, Petron will be bankrupt by now and will thus fail in its obligation that the author stated: “It [Petron] was the most profitable government corporation and thus a valuable source of revenues for government. More important, Petron performed a unique role in stabilizing local oil prices” (177). The author recognized that he could not have insulated Petron from political intervention and government rules and regulations if it were not for Martial Law (29).

I submit that the privatization of Petron and the oil deregulation law are the right policies under the current political environment, but I agree with the author that the government must strengthen its regulatory powers and exercise it to the fullest. Deregulation does not mean no regulation but re-regulation. For starters, one advantage of deregulation would be that all service stations, not only of Petron, would have clean toilets (168).

Congress needs to pass an anti-trust law so that it can strengthen its regulatory mandate in liberalized and deregulated markets. Even if the government has only a 40 percent share in Petron, this can still be used as a policy instrument and exert influence in pricing. However, government would need political savvy in addition to management acumen.

The author admits that during his term, everybody followed Petron when it set the price (194). The same happens in a deregulated environment: Everybody follows the lowest price setter, hence the “same price” situation still prevails, but that same price is the lowest price set by the most efficient. While one is always free to accuse the foreign companies of collusion, I do not think that Petron is a party even with Saudi Aramco as a foreign partner. Otherwise, government itself, which has equal vote in the board, will be a party to a cartel, which it wants to prevent—an irony in its highest degree. The privatization model of Petron achieves the twin objectives of insulating it from political intervention and performing its role as “a potent policy instrument” vis-à-vis major oil industry players.

To be able to perform its role well, Petron had to be financially stable, efficient, and able to compete; but this is possible only if it is insulated from political intervention. Given the current political climate, its privatization, with government retaining 40 percent and the public 20 percent, is the best decision that was made by the Ramos administration.

Likewise, the Philippine Electric Power Industry Reform Act (EPIRA), for all its shortcomings, is a step in the right direction. The government has no money to put into the required expansion program of the power sector, and with political intervention Napocor cannot generate its cash counterpart requirements for the projects (136). Lower interest loans are offset by inefficiency and political interference. EPIRA is a developmental process and the issue of cross-ownership prohibition must come at the right time. For this, government must be constantly at attention to monitor developments on monopolistic behavior. National Transmission Corporation, for instance, must be privatized like the Petron model. It must not be entrusted completely in the hands of the private sector, even in a concessionaire model of privatization.

The author failed to mention that our independent power producer contracts are, in reality, not IPP contracts in the strictest sense, but are Build-Operate-Transfer contracts (a policy embodied in Republic Act [RA] 6957 and RA 7718) wherein the assets will be transferred to the Napocor after the cooperation period. As such, the payments made due to the “take-or-pay” contract, whether used or not, are payments for the capital assets and not for unused fuel or coal because Napocor supplies the fuel. Note that the author’s word is “whether or not the organization needed” (155) instead of used, to which I disagree with because at the time the take-or-pay volume were contracted out, they were based on forecast and therefore were “needed” in the future as forecasted at that time. Unlike a straightforward IPP, the facilities are not transferred to the buying party. So in the BOT projects, payments made if the plants are not used is not wasted because the assets will eventually be owned by Napocor.

Lastly, to say that the post-Marcos administration did not have a comprehensive energy development plan is a sweeping statement. I would like to take exception for the Ramos administration for which I was the Secretary of Energy from September 1994. In fact, the plans and programs of the Ramos administration were built on the achievements mentioned in the book; and the policies, objectives, and basic thrusts were basically maintained (208). Policies on the development of indigenous energy resources and renewable energy and energy conservation were continued. We pursued the implementation of the Malampaya natural gas project, which has enhanced our energy security and independence. We left behind an ocean, solar, and wind pole-vaulting program, which is geared toward developing renewable energy. We had the very successful Power Patrol Project, which involved the participation of the private sector to support the energy conservation policy.

The policy on deregulation and liberalization of the oil and power industry are policies called for in this current form of political governance. Liberalization is not an invention of post-Marcos administrations because as the author wrote, “In 1984, as the country implemented the International Monetary Fund’s structural adjustment program, we [the Marcos administration] had to allow market forces to operate in the coal industry” (65-66). Moreover, the Ramos administration left behind a thirty-five-year Energy Development Plan (1998-2035), which takes off from the accomplishments cited in the book and those done during the Ramos administration.

The Filipino people are now enjoying the fruits of the labor of the author in our quest for energy self-reliance, most especially the geothermal and hydropower development. But while he does not agree with the privatization of Petron, we must realize that Petron’s privatization was successful because it was nurtured and managed well to become a very profitable company during the Marcos administration. While we have yet to see the benefits of the EPIRA, it is too early to pass judgment on policy decisions of post-Marcos administrations on the power sector. Suffice it to say that I agree with the author that the success of deregulating a very critical industry, like oil and power, is a strengthened, responsive, and well-administered regulatory environment. The challenge that lies ahead of us is to be able to duplicate the achievements told in the book in our own version of democracy in which political intervention, not only by the politicians but also by those with self-interests from the private sector and nongovernment organizations, is a commonplace.—Francisco L. Viray, President, Trans-Asia Power Generation Corporation

4 comments:

Anonymous said...

So.... what's the point? Is the point that Marcos was evil, or is it that the Philippines should go nuclear?

Anonymous said...

Who knows where to download XRumer 5.0 Palladium?
Help, please. All recommend this program to effectively advertise on the Internet, this is the best program!

Anonymous said...

Drug sustiva Low price avandia No prescription depakote Online imuran Online xeloda 10mg singulair

Anonymous said...

Hello!
You may probably be very interested to know how one can manage to receive high yields on investments.
There is no need to invest much at first.
You may commense to get income with a sum that usually goes
on daily food, that's 20-100 dollars.
I have been participating in one project for several years,
and I'm ready to let you know my secrets at my blog.

Please visit blog and send me private message to get the info.

P.S. I earn 1000-2000 per day now.

http://theinvestblog.com [url=http://theinvestblog.com]Online Investment Blog[/url]